Dr. Robin Dhakal
Trade has been the lifeblood of human civilization for thousands
of years. From the barter systems of ancient tribes to the complex global
supply chains of today, the exchange of goods and services has shaped
economies, cultures, and nations. But what makes trade so powerful? And why has
the concept of free trade become a cornerstone of modern economics?
But first, a brief history…
Trade is as old as human society itself. Ancient
civilizations like Mesopotamia, Egypt, and the Indus Valley were among the
first to engage in organized trade, exchanging goods such as grain, spices,
textiles, and precious metals. One of the most famous examples of early global
trade is the Silk Road, a sprawling network of routes that connected Asia to
Europe from around 130 BCE to the 1450s CE. The Silk Road facilitated the
exchange of silk, spices, tea, and other luxury goods, but its impact went far
beyond material wealth. It enabled the flow of knowledge, art, and innovation,
linking the Roman Empire, China, India, and the Islamic world. For instance,
papermaking, gunpowder, and the compass—technologies that originated in
China—spread to Europe via these routes, profoundly shaping the course of
history. In the Middle Ages, city-states like Venice and Genoa became wealthy
through trade, while the Age of Exploration in the 15th and 16th centuries
opened up new trade routes between Europe, Asia, and the Americas. The
discovery of the Americas, in particular, opened up unprecedented trade
opportunities, with goods like sugar, tobacco, and silver flowing into Europe.
However, this period also saw the darker side of trade, including the
transatlantic slave trade and the exploitation of colonized regions.
Despite the growth of trade, it was often constrained by
mercantilist policies, which dominated economic thought from the 16th to the
18th centuries. Mercantilism viewed trade as a zero-sum game, where nations
sought to accumulate wealth by maximizing exports and minimizing imports, often
through tariffs and trade restrictions. This approach prioritized national
power over mutual benefit, setting the stage for the economic theories that
would later challenge it.
In comes Adam Smith
The modern concept of free trade began to take shape in the
18th century, thanks to the groundbreaking work of Scottish economist Adam
Smith. In his landmark book The Wealth of Nations (1776), Smith challenged the
prevailing economic doctrine of mercantilism, which viewed trade as a
competition where one nation’s gain was another’s loss. Instead, Smith
introduced the idea of absolute advantage, arguing that trade could be a
win-win situation for all nations involved.
Smith’s key insight was simple yet revolutionary: countries
should focus on producing goods they can make more efficiently—that is, at a
lower cost or with fewer resources—than other countries, and then trade for the
rest. This specialization, he argued, would lead to greater productivity, lower
costs, and increased wealth for everyone. To understand why this was such a
radical idea at the time, imagine two countries: England and France. Suppose
England is really good at producing wool—it can make a lot of wool quickly and
cheaply—while France is really good at producing wine. Under mercantilism, both
countries might try to produce both wool and wine on their own, even if they’re
not very good at one of them. This would be inefficient and costly.
Smith’s idea of absolute advantage flipped this logic on its
head. He said, “Why should England waste resources trying to produce wine when
it’s so much better at making wool? And why should France struggle to produce
wool when it excels at making wine?” Instead, Smith proposed that England
should focus on producing wool and France should focus on producing wine. Then,
they could trade with each other. England would get all the wine it needed from
France, and France would get all the wool it needed from England. Both
countries would end up with more of both goods at a lower cost than if they
tried to produce everything themselves.
Smith’s theory laid the foundation for the modern
understanding of free trade, showing that open markets and specialization could
drive economic growth and improve living standards. It was a radical departure
from the zero-sum thinking of mercantilism and set the stage for the global
trade systems we have today.
David Ricardo- the true champion of free trade
While Adam Smith’s theory of absolute advantage was
groundbreaking, it was David Ricardo who took the concept of trade to a whole
new level with his idea of comparative advantage. In his 1817 work On the
Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ricardo showed that even if one
country is more efficient at producing all goods, trade can still benefit both
countries—as long as they specialize in producing the goods where they have the
relative efficiency advantage. This idea was so powerful that it became the
cornerstone of modern trade theory.
To understand why comparative advantage is such a
game-changer, let’s revisit our example of England and Portugal. Suppose
Portugal is better than England at producing both wine and cloth. Under Adam
Smith’s absolute advantage theory, it might seem like Portugal has no reason to
trade with England because it can produce everything more efficiently. But
Ricardo saw something deeper: even if Portugal is better at both, it’s still
better for Portugal to focus on the good where its advantage is greatest and
let England handle the other.
Here’s how it works: Imagine Portugal can produce 10 bottles
of wine or 5 yards of cloth in the same amount of time, while England can
produce only 2 bottles of wine or 4 yards of cloth. Portugal is clearly better
at both, but its advantage in wine production is much greater than in cloth.
Ricardo argued that Portugal should focus on making wine, where its efficiency
is highest, and England should focus on making cloth, where its inefficiency is
least. By specializing and trading, both countries end up with more wine and
cloth than if they tried to produce everything on their own.
Why is this so revolutionary? Because it shows that trade
isn’t just about being the best—it’s about making the most of what you have.
Even if one country is worse at producing everything, it can still benefit from
trade by focusing on what it’s least bad at. This means trade isn’t just for
the most efficient economies; it’s for everyone. It’s a win-win situation,
where both sides gain by doing what they’re relatively better at.
Ricardo’s concept of comparative advantage is why trade
agreements exist today. It proves that trade isn’t a zero-sum game where one
side wins and the other loses. Instead, it’s a way for countries to work
together, leveraging their unique strengths to create more wealth for everyone.
This idea is so powerful that economists still call it “the most beautiful idea
in economics.” It’s not just a theory—it’s the reason why free trade has lifted
millions out of poverty and transformed the global economy.
Success stories
One of the most compelling examples of free trade’s benefits
is the post-World War II economic boom. In 1947, 23 nations signed the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which laid the foundation for modern
free trade by reducing tariffs and trade barriers. Over the next few decades,
GATT’s successor, the World Trade Organization (WTO), continued to push for
freer markets, contributing to an unprecedented rise in global trade. Between
1950 and 2022, world trade expanded 32-fold, significantly outpacing global GDP
growth. This trade expansion lifted millions out of poverty, particularly in
developing nations like China, India, and Vietnam.
The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), implemented
in 1994 and renegotiated in 2018 as the United States- Mexico- Canada Agreement
(USMCA) is a prime example of free trade’s success. Before NAFTA, trade between
the U.S., Canada, and Mexico was hindered by tariffs and trade restrictions. By
eliminating these barriers, NAFTA helped increase trilateral trade from $290
billion in 1993 to over $1.2 trillion by 2016. The agreement also created
millions of jobs: for example, U.S. exports to Mexico supported nearly 1.2
million American jobs by 2015. Additionally, consumers in all three countries
benefited from lower prices on goods like automobiles and agricultural products
due to increased efficiency and competition.
Similarly, the European Union’s single market, which allows
free movement of goods, services, capital, and labor among its 27 member
states, has been a resounding success. Since its full implementation in 1993,
intra-EU trade has nearly tripled, and the region has become the world's
second-largest economy. The single market has increased EU GDP by an estimated
9%, benefiting businesses and consumers alike. For instance, German car
manufacturers like Volkswagen and French agricultural producers have been able
to expand their reach without trade barriers, resulting in more jobs and
economic growth.
Beyond these large-scale agreements, individual nations have
also reaped the rewards of free trade. China’s accession to the WTO in 2001
marked a turning point in global trade dynamics. By reducing tariffs and
opening its markets, China experienced explosive economic growth, with exports
rising from $266 billion in 2001 to $2.5 trillion in 2018. This transformation
lifted over 800 million people out of poverty and turned China into the world’s
manufacturing powerhouse. Similarly, Vietnam’s embrace of free trade, through
agreements like the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), helped it become one of
the fastest-growing economies in the world, with exports surging from $14
billion in 2000 to over $330 billion in 2022.
Free trade has also significantly benefited consumers by
reducing costs and improving access to essential goods. For example, tariffs on
electronics and textiles have been lowered globally, allowing smartphones,
computers, and clothing to become more affordable. The rise of global supply
chains, enabled by free trade agreements, has driven down the cost of
manufacturing, making products like iPhones and laptops accessible to billions.
While free trade has its critics, the overwhelming evidence
shows that it has been a key driver of global economic growth, job creation,
and poverty reduction over the past century. By enabling specialization,
fostering competition, and expanding markets, free trade has not only improved
national economies but also enhanced the quality of life for millions
worldwide.
Tariffs!
Despite the benefits of free trade, tariffs—taxes on
imported goods—have been used throughout history. Governments often impose
tariffs to protect domestic industries from foreign competition, generate
revenue, or address trade imbalances. However, tariffs come with significant
downsides.
The U.S. Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 is one of the most
infamous examples of protectionism. Aiming to shield American farmers during
the Great Depression, it raised tariffs on thousands of imported goods. Instead
of reviving the economy, it provoked retaliatory tariffs from other countries,
causing a collapse in international trade and deepening the global economic
downturn.
In more recent history, the U.S.-China trade war (2018-2020)
saw both countries imposing tariffs on hundreds of billions of dollars worth of
goods. The U.S. sought to reduce its trade deficit and counter China’s trade
practices by imposing tariffs on Chinese goods, leading China to respond with
its own tariffs. While intended to protect domestic industries, these measures
led to higher costs for businesses and consumers, disrupted global supply
chains, and slowed economic growth. In 2019 alone, estimates suggested that the
trade war cost the U.S. economy around $316 billion and slowed global GDP
growth by 0.8%.
Similarly, Brexit led to the reintroduction of trade
barriers between the UK and the European Union. The UK’s departure from the EU
single market resulted in new tariffs and customs checks, which disrupted trade
flows and increased costs for businesses. Studies indicate that Brexit-related
trade frictions have reduced UK exports to the EU by approximately 15% since
2020.
While tariffs can offer short-term protection for certain
industries, history shows that their long-term consequences—higher consumer
prices, trade retaliation, and economic slowdowns—often outweigh their
benefits. Thus, many economists argue that freer trade, with carefully
negotiated agreements, remains the best path for sustained global prosperity.
Why do economists say tariffs are bad?
Tariffs distort market dynamics by artificially raising the
cost of imported goods, leading to inefficiencies and reduced consumer choice.
When a government imposes tariffs, it forces consumers to pay more for goods
that would otherwise be cheaper, essentially acting as a hidden tax. For
example, if the U.S. imposes tariffs on imported washing machines, the cost of
these appliances rises, making it more expensive for families to replace old or
broken ones. This not only reduces the purchasing power of consumers but also
disproportionately hurts lower-income households, who spend a higher percentage
of their income on everyday goods. In addition, businesses facing higher costs
for raw materials and goods pass these costs on to consumers. For example, US-imposed
tariffs on Chinese imports between 2018 and 2019 resulted in an average cost
increase of $1,300 per U.S. household, according to the Peterson Institute for
International Economics. This inflationary effect ripples through the economy,
making everything from groceries to cars more expensive. Unlike targeted
subsidies or investments in innovation, tariffs act as a blunt instrument that
raises costs without addressing underlying economic inefficiencies.
Tariffs also invite retaliation, sparking trade wars that
harm all parties involved. When one country imposes tariffs, affected trading
partners often respond with their own tariffs, escalating costs across multiple
industries. A clear example of this was the U.S.-China trade war, where tariffs
imposed on Chinese goods led to increased prices on products like electronics,
clothing, and furniture. In response, China retaliated with tariffs on U.S.
agricultural exports, severely impacting American farmers who relied on global
markets.
Moreover, tariffs often protect inefficient domestic
industries at the expense of more competitive sectors, stifling innovation and
long-term growth. A striking example is the U.S. steel tariffs imposed in 2002,
which temporarily helped domestic steel producers but severely harmed
industries that rely on steel, such as automotive and construction companies.
As steel prices surged, car manufacturers and construction firms faced higher
production costs, leading to job losses in those sectors. Estimates suggest
that while the tariffs saved approximately 3,500 steel industry jobs, they
resulted in the loss of nearly 200,000 jobs in steel-consuming industries due
to increased costs.
Free trade has been a driving force behind global
prosperity, enabling nations to specialize, innovate, and grow. While tariffs
have their place in history, they often do more harm than good in the long run.
As the world becomes increasingly interconnected, the case for free trade
remains stronger than ever. By embracing open markets and cooperation, nations
can continue to reap the benefits of trade, creating a more prosperous and
interconnected world.
Dr. Robin Dhakal is an Assistant Professor in the Forbes School of Business and Technology. He earned an M.A. and a Ph.D. in Economics from the University of South Florida and a B.A. in Business/Economics and Mathematics/Computer Science from Warren Wilson College. His academic research focuses on development economics and political economy. He has been teaching Economics in colleges and universities for the past ten years. You can reach him at
robin.dhakal@uagc.edu
References:
Britannica. (n.d.). Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act. In Encyclopedia
Britannica. Retrieved from https://www.britannica.com/topic/Smoot-Hawley-Tariff-Act
Bureau of Economic Analysis. (2019). U.S. trade in goods
and services by selected countries and areas. U.S. Department of Commerce. https://www.bea.gov/data/intl-trade-investment/international-trade-goods-and-services
Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2019). The effects of tariff
rates on the U.S. economy: What the Producer Price Index tells us. Beyond
the Numbers: Prices and Spending, 8(1). https://www.bls.gov/opub/btn/volume-9/the-effects-of-tarifff-rates-on-the-u-s-economy-what-the-producer-price-index-tells-us.htm
Fajgelbaum, P., & Khandelwal, A. (2021). The economic
impacts of the US-China trade war. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Retrieved from https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w29315/w29315.pdf
Francois, J., & Baughman, L. M. (2003). The
unintended consequences of U.S. steel import tariffs: A quantification of the
impact during 2002. Trade Partnership Worldwide, LLC. Prepared for the
CITAC Foundation.
Johns, B., Brenton, P., Piermartini, R., Sadni Jallab, M.,
& Teh, R. (2018). Trade and poverty reduction: New evidence of impacts
in developing countries (English). World Bank Group. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/968461544478747599/Trade-and-Poverty-Reduction-New-Evidence-of-Impacts-in-Developing-Countries
Krugman, P., Obstfeld, M., & Melitz, M. J. (2018). International
economics: Theory and policy (11th ed.). Pearson.
Peterson Institute for International Economics. (2019). US-China
trade war tariffs: An up-to-date chart. Retrieved from https://www.piie.com/research/piie-charts/2019/us-china-trade-war-tariffs-date-chart
Tax Foundation. (2021). Section 232 tariffs on steel and
aluminum. Retrieved from https://taxfoundation.org/research/all/federal/section-232-tariffs-steel-aluminum/
Tax Foundation. (2025). Trump tariffs: Tracking the
economic impact of the Trump trade war. Retrieved from https://taxfoundation.org/research/all/federal/trump-tariffs-trade-war/
U.S. Census Bureau. (2017). Trade in goods with Mexico.
Retrieved from https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c2010.html
VoxEU. (2020). The 'bystander effect' of the US-China
trade war. Centre for Economic Policy Research. Retrieved from https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/bystander-effect-us-china-trade-war
World Trade Organization. (2019). Global trade report:
Trends and statistics. Retrieved from https://www.wto-ilibrary.org/content/books/9789287047755/read
World Trade Organization. (2020). An economic analysis of
the US-China trade conflict (WTO Working Paper No. 2020/04). World Trade
Organization. https://doi.org/10.30875/5b611474-en